Some notes on the role of ideas in economic growth and the paper Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?
Progress studies conference slides
resource constraint - the limitations imposed on the production and consumption of goods and services due to the finite availability of resources such as labor, capital, and raw materials.
endogenous growth model - a type of economic model where the long-term rate of economic growth is primarily determined by internal factors within the economy such as human capital accumulation, innovation, and knowledge spillovers rather than external influences.
balanced growth path - where we assume all key economic variables e.g. output , capital , consumption , and technology level grow at constant, proportional rates over time, and crucial ratios between these variables remain constant.
Why are ideas important for economic growth? There are some bullet points on slide 3 of the slides. I like the explanation that Jose gives in part 0.1 of his piece here.
The number of new ideas we find is bounded by the number of people looking for ideas.
It's quite easy to describe a model based off this assumption that explains the minimal growth before the industrial revolution as well as the hockey stick and sustained growth we've seen since then: The population rises on the back of an idea and then falls back to subsistence levels of wealth. However there are now more people which shortens the time it takes for a new idea to emerge. Eventually ideas are arriving fast enough that incomes rise before the population as time to expand and fall back to subsistence.
Components of growth in the past included things like rising education levels, rising workforce participation, and declining misallocation. As those go away ideas as a function of population growth are all that remain.
This has potentially troubling implications for the future if the population plateaus and falls unless something like AI comes to the rescue.
Before then though, it is worth asking if ideas are themselves getting harder to find.
Note: equation numbers are copied from the paper to make it easier to cross-reference.
Let's begin by defining some variables:
You can define the productivity of the idea production function as the ratio of the output of ideas to the inputs used to make them:
The equation at the heart of many growth models is an idea production function of the form:
This says that the growth rate of the economy, through the production of new ideas, is proportional to the number of researchers. When we model the economy this way we are assuming that research productivity is constant over time - an equivalent number of researchers is all that is required to maintain an exponential rate of growth. The authors present evidence that within narrow categories such as a firm or product line research productivity is not constant but in fact declines over time. They then raise the question of whether research productivity is sustained by ideas in one product line leading to ideas in another. They observe that in aggregate the exponential rate of growth in GDP and total factor productivity in the US economy has remained roughly stable or even declined since 1870 and 1930 respectively. This despite the huge increase in research effort over that time.
Suppose the economy at a particular time produces different products and each product is associated with some quality level .
Innovation can lead the quality of each product to rise over time according to an idea production function.
where is the number of scientists improving the quality of some product at time .
In the case where the number of scientists and number of products are growing, the number of scientists per product could be flat . So for each product the rate at which new ideas are produced remains constant over time. But when we look at the whole economy in aggregate it might look like we need more and more scientists to keep up the same overall growth rate, making it seem like research is becoming less productive.
So the authors argue that it's important to study the idea production function at the micro level and look at research productivity for individual products:
When measuring "research effort" it's common to measure expenditure on R&D, as opposed to the number of researchers. The former:
This is known as a lab equipment model because implicitly both capital and labor are used as inputs to produce ideas.
In lab equipment models, endogenous growth occurs when the idea production function takes the form
where is measured in units of a final output good.
Consider a single good economy. Suppose the final output good is produced with a standard Cobb-Douglas production function
where:
represents the output elasticity of capital or, equivalently, capital’s share in production. This means:
In this production function the exponents and sum up to 1, implying constant returns to scale. So if you double both capital and effective labor inputs, output will also double.
The resource constraint for this economy is
where:
So final output is used for a combination of consumption, investment, and research.
Combining these three equations gives us the endogenous growth result. Dividing both sides of the production function above by and rearranging gives:
Start with the original production function:
Divide both sides by :
We can simplify the left side because :
On the right side therefore:
Divide both sides by to isolate the terms involving :
Simplify the left side using the fact that :
Raise both sides to the power to eliminate the exponent on the left side:
Multiply both sides by to solve for :
Letting denote the share of the final good spent on research, the idea production function can be expressed as
This can easily be rearranged to
What are the implications of the last equation?
How should we define research productivity in the idea production function? We can deflate R&D expenditure by wage to get a measure of "effective scientists". Letting be the wage for labour in the economy, the idea production function can be written as
We start with the idea production function in equation (10)
Divide both sides by
This expresses the proportional growth rate of technology in terms of R&D expenditures relative to the current technology level.
To introduce the wage rate into the equation, we can multiply and divide the right-hand side by :
where the terms on the right hand side are:
We can do some algebra here to express research effort in terms of:
On a balanced growth path, key economic ratios remain constant over time. If , , and are constant, then will also be constant. This implies that the effective number of scientists remains constant even as the economy grows, aligning with the predictions of standard endogenous growth models.
The idea production function can then be written as:
We define adjusted research productivity as
This captures research productivity per unit wage, adjusted for the current technology level.
We also use our definition for of effective number of scientists
This gives us
where both and will be constant in the long run under the null hypothesis of endogenous growth. We can therefore define research productivity in the lab equipment setup in a way that parallels our earlier treatment:
The only difference is that we deflate R&D expenditures by a measure of the nominal wage to get . Deflating R&D spending by the nominal wages is important. If we did not and instead naively computed research productivity by dividing by we would find that research productivity was falling because of the rise in , even in the endogenous growth case. Most other idea-driven growth models in the literature predict that ideas per research dollar is declining; the theory in this paper suggests that ideas per researcher is a much more informative measure.
An easy intuition for the last equation is this:
Researchers needed to produce a Moore's law doubling in semi conductors.
Agricultural productivity (corn, soybeans, cotton, and wheat). Research productivity for seed yields declines at about 5 percent per year.
Medical innovations - They find a similar rate of decline when studying the mortality improvements associated with cancer and heart disease.
Research productivity in firm level data.
Are these ideas getting harder to find just "academic" ideas? Venture capitalists fund ideas that are either worth ~nothing or a lot. Shouldn't VC returns go down if ideas are getting harder to find? It would be interesting to try and replicate the paper's predictions on a dataset of VC performance if one could be found.
How predictive is the model? For instance, how do we explain extremely productive small clusters vs places with larger populations that achieved nothing?
Are things being reclassified? It feels like this is the sort of thing where what counts as a new idea could be doing quite a lot of the work.
What if the number of scientists is constant but they reshuffle the areas they focus on as new ideas arise. You would then get a decreasing number of scientists working on old products so their quality would remain constant but more scientists working on new products where new ideas are more easily found. In that model, would we expect a constant number of scientists to sustain a constant rate of growth? Then an increase in new scientists would be enough to sustain an exponential?
Matt Clancy proposes the "burden of knowledge" as one possible explanation.
Maxwell Tabarrok argues that the paper provides evidence for a slowdown in R&D progress but not that it is caused by ideas becoming harder to find. He is also sceptical that the burden of knowledge is enough to explain everything.
Tags: Economics